Peterson Institute publications
The Peterson Institute for International Economics is a private, nonprofit, nonpartisan
research institution devoted to the study of international economic policy. More › ›
RSS News Feed Search

Op-ed

The Virtues of Self-Restraint

by Adam S. Posen, Peterson Institute for International Economics

Op-ed in Central Banking (XVII: 4)
April 18, 2007


One of the greatest strengths of the Bank of England’s regime since independence has been its narrowness of mission. The bank is there to deliver price stability over the medium-term, subject to due concern for short-term output volatility and financial instability, full stop. It no longer is concerned with financial supervision writ broadly, and it is not an ongoing contributor to public debates outside its monetary policy remit.

With focus comes clarity. Both internally and externally, the concentration of the bank on its core role has given it greater authority to carry out its monetary policy mandate. Internally, there is little question about priorities, and thus little waste of resources or nonsubstantive disagreements. Externally, this strengthens the anchoring of inflation expectations and reinforces the bank’s independence because it distances the bank from extraneous or political disputes. On both fronts, clarity of mission has enhanced the sense of accountability of the bank for its performance of that mission.

The bank’s narrowing of focus has hardly been uncontroversial. Some have expressed concern that independence has constrained senior bank officials’ ability to make valuable public comments on other areas of economic policy. Others have a judoesque worry that somehow the bank’s wresting of independence from Her Majesty’s Treasury has given the Chancellor more autonomy on fiscal policy and financial matters.

Politicians abroad have tried to prevent other central banks from following the bank’s example in this regard. When Ben Bernanke made some noises in this direction upon his nomination to be Federal Reserve Chairman in December 2005, that he would be more restrained in his statements on nonmonetary issues than his predecessor, a number of US senators from both parties publicly asked him to reconsider.

Yet, these fears have proven unfounded in the United Kingdom over the last decade. This is best illustrated by the bank’s consciously limited role in the 2002–03 discussion of whether the Chancellor’s “Five Tests” for euro entry were met. There was a very lively public debate on all aspects of the tests, including whether they were the right ones; the bank’s staff contributed technical expertise to The Treasury’s evaluation but was not seen as making any judgments or taking any stands; inflation expectations and market stability were unaffected by this debate, in large measure because it was clear the bank’s monetary decision making was not distracted by the euro entry issue; the Chancellor and the elected Labour government were correctly held accountable for the decision without interference from unelected “Mandarins,” and the bank suffered no politicization or pressure as a result. This salutary outcome is something which is difficult to imagine would have been possible in the days before independence, say in 1992.

The places where central banks are called upon to weigh in on a host of issues beyond monetary policy are almost always those where the economic policy apparatus is seen as untrustworthy or incapable. So, in less developed countries where there was often a lack of economic expertise and of uncorrupted administrators, the governor and staff of the central bank would be the one place that well-intentioned politicians, markets, and outside lenders like the International Monetary Fund and World Bank could turn.

Similarly, even in advanced economies, where political instability made government commitments (particularly on fiscal policy) less than credible, the central bank and its presumably apolitical staff would become a source of economic conscience—as seen in the role of the Banca d’Italia in the 1980s and early 1990s. In short, a broadly active central bank is a marker of weakness in an economy’s policymaking.

The Bank of England’s focus since independence on its core competency and mission of monetary policy is thus a sign of the United Kingdom’s economic strength and political credibility. To the bank’s, and in particular the current Governor, Mervyn King’s, credit, the concentration on what monetary policy can and cannot do has been the result of enlightened self-restraint—it was not the inevitable result of independence. It was the bank itself that initiated shedding its bank supervisory responsibility, and it has been Governor King and successive Monetary Policy Committees that have restrained their own interjections into policy issues outside their core mission.

That virtuous self-restraint has paid off. For the bank, it has meant further insulation from political pressure because of its increased reputation for nonpartisanship and its obvious lack of desire to extend its range of influence. For the UK policymaking process as a whole, it has set a standard of discipline, clarity, and accountability that has caused the rest of the government to raise its game. As I argued when the trend for central bank independence began, independence will only be sustained where the central bank builds a constituency in civil society supporting that autonomy1 —and the Bank of England’s clarity of mission has built that constituency, while delivering price stability, in a way that other European central banks currently under attack can only envy.


Note

1. Posen, Adam S. 1993. Why Central Bank Independence Does Not Cause Low Infla­tion: There is no Institu­tional Fix for Politics. In Finance and the International Economy: 7 , ed. Richard O'Brien. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 40–65.


RELATED LINKS

Policy Brief 13-29: Estimates of Fundamental Equilibrium Exchange Rates, November 2013 November 2013

Policy Brief 13-28: Stabilizing Properties of Flexible Exchange Rates: Evidence from the Global Financial Crisis November 2013

Op-ed: Unconventional Monetary Policy: Don't Shoot the Messenger November 14, 2013

Op-ed: Misconceptions About Fed's Bond Buying September 2, 2013

Working Paper 13-2: The Elephant Hiding in the Room: Currency Intervention and Trade Imbalances March 2013

Policy Brief 12-25: Currency Manipulation, the US Economy, and the Global Economic Order December 2012

Working Paper 12-19: The Renminbi Bloc Is Here: Asia Down, Rest of the World to Go? October 2012
Revised August 2013

Policy Brief 12-19: Combating Widespread Currency Manipulation July 2012

Policy Brief 12-7: Projecting China's Current Account Surplus April 2012

Working Paper 12-4: Spillover Effects of Exchange Rates: A Study of the Renminbi March 2012

Book: Flexible Exchange Rates for a Stable World Economy October 2011

Op-ed: Taxing China's Assets: How to Increase US Employment Without Launching a Trade War April 25, 2011

Op-ed: Why the World Needs Three Global Currencies February 15, 2011

Policy Brief 10-24: The Central Banker's Case for Doing More October 2010

Policy Brief 10-26: Currency Wars? November 2010

Testimony: Correcting the Chinese Exchange Rate September 15, 2010

Op-ed: New Imbalances Will Threaten Global Recovery June 10, 2010

Book: The Future of China's Exchange Rate Policy July 2009

Book: Debating China's Exchange Rate Policy April 2008

Article: The Dollar and the Deficits: How Washington Can Prevent the Next Crisis November 2009

Policy Brief 09-21: The Future of the Dollar September 2009

Policy Brief 07-4: Global Imbalances: Time for Action March 2007

Working Paper 11-14: Renminbi Rules: The Conditional Imminence of the Reserve Currency Transition September 2011

Peterson Perspective: Legislation to Sanction China: Will It Work? October 7, 2011

Book: China's Rise: Challenges and Opportunities (hardcover) September 2008